by Eric Englund
"The
truth is that the State is a conspiracy designed not only
to exploit, but above all to corrupt its citizens."
Leo Tolstoy
"None
are more hopelessly enslaved than those who falsely believe
they are free." Johann Wolfgang von Goethe
In 1912,
Ludwig von Mises's masterwork The
Theory of Money and Credit was published; and to this
day, this book is underappreciated. How can this be? After
all, in this book, Mises unveiled his regression theorem demonstrating
commodity money, such as gold, can have its purchasing power
traced back in time to the point where gold was not a medium
of exchange. Mises, accordingly, eliminated the conundrum
in which the marginal-utility explanation of money demand
would merely be a case of circular reasoning; money emerged
out of barter and his logic is irrefutable. Mises also laid
the foundation for the Austrian theory of the trade cycle,
which correctly deduces that economic boom-bust cycles are
caused by inflationary bank-credit expansion as enabled by
central banks and their governments. While writing The
Theory of Money and Credit, Mises was pondering the issue
of economic calculation in a socialist state. Per
Murray Rothbard,
Mises
writes that he was led to consider the socialist calculation
problem by his work on The Theory of Money and Credit.
Here Mises realized for the first time with keen clarity
that the money economy does not and cannot calculate or
measure values directly: that it only calculates with money
prices, the resultants of such individual valuations. Hence,
Mises realized that only a market with money prices based
on the evaluations and exchanges of private owners can rationally
allocate resources, since there is no way by which a government
could calculate values directly. Hence, for Mises his article
and book on socialism was part and parcel of the development
of his expanded integration of micro and macro, of direct
monetary exchange, that he had begun but not completed in
The Theory of Money and Credit.[1]
Without
private ownership in the means of production, economic calculation
is impossible. Per Joseph T. Salerno, "a single human mind
... would be utterly incapable of determining the optimal
pattern of resource allocation or even if a particular plan
were ludicrously and destructively uneconomic."[2]
To be sure, the collapse of the USSR demonstrated the harmful,
resource-misallocating, and uneconomic nature of the socialist
state.
Ludwig
von Mises, indisputably, was correct about the inherent irrationality
of the socialist state. Because Mises, however, grudgingly
believed in the necessity of the state, he did not extend
his critique to the irrational essence of the state itself
after all, he believed that government was necessary
for providing national defense, courts, prisons, and police
protection/security.[3]
He did not see free-market solutions emerging in lieu of these
state-provided services.
Given
the nature of all states, is it not true that government entities
are incapable of rationally allocating resources? In a socialist
state, an economy cannot emerge due to the impossibility of
economic calculation under collective ownership of the means
of production, as prices for production goods cannot materialize.
Owing to the character of all states, however, it is impossible
for bureaucratic operatives to rationally allocate resources,
which is due to the impossibility of applying a profit-and-loss
test to the operations of the state. Such impossibility arises
as a state's revenues are based not on voluntary market exchanges
but are based on coercion mostly via taxation. In a world
of scarcity, it stands to reason that entities which misallocate
resources and destroy capital are fundamentally irrational
and undesirable. Any entity that comes into existence based
on coercion and theft and then is incapable of rationally
allocating resources under its control is criminal in nature
and harmful to mankind. This entity is the state.
The
State Is Anticapital
Capital
is wealth, in whatever form, and is used or is capable of
being used to produce additional wealth. Farmland, seeds,
tools, buildings, and draft animals are examples of capital
that predate the emergence of the state. Just as there was
a day when gold emerged as money, there was a day where the
state was born. It is axiomatic, however, that capital existed
prior to the emergence of the state. As Linda and Morris Tannehill
wrote,
Wealth
does not exist in nature but must be created. The only means
of creating wealth is value-production and free exchange
the manufacture and trade of some desired good or
service. One may obtain wealth directly, by productive work,
or one may obtain it indirectly, by looting it from a producer,
but the wealth must be created by production in the first
place in order to exist at all.[4]
For man
to satisfy his needs and desires, there are the economic means
and the political means.[5]
Correspondingly, the "state is an organization of the political
means. No state, therefore, can come into being until the
economic means has created a definite number of objects for
satisfaction of needs, which objects may be taken away or
appropriated by warlike robbery."[6]
The state, consequently, was born on coercion, expropriation,
theft, and violence.
The most
aggressive expropriator of wealth is the socialist state.
Under socialism, the state takes ownership of all means of
production, including land. Prior to the emergence of the
socialist state, for example in the USSR, much of the means
of production and land were privately owned. On the formation
of the USSR, all means of production and land were collectivized
and, therefore, brought under control of the Soviet Union's
central planners. A more accurate way to describe this collectivization
process is to call it for what it is: state-sponsored coercion
and theft on the grandest scale known to mankind.
After
74 years of existence, the Soviet Union collapsed, thereby
exposing socialism's devastation to its people, resources,
and capital. "As the Soviet Union came to an end, the public
had been reduced to a collective of hunter gatherers, barely
existing at a subsistence level."[7]
The total state, as exemplified by the Soviet Union, led to
the total impoverishment of its people not to mention
that it murdered approximately 20 million of its own citizens.[8]
Although
states openly steal property, there are varying degrees of
"respect" states concede with regard to private-property ownership.
People in the United States, for instance, feel relatively
secure in their ownership of private property. It is, nonetheless,
a grey area as to who owns land and houses in the United States.
For if someone fails to pay property taxes, then the taxing
authority can legally confiscate the house or tract of land.
Moreover, the 16th Amendment to the US Constitution allows
for direct taxation and, therefore, Uncle Sam has claimed
prior ownership to the fruits of everyone's labor in the United
States. Money is property, just as much as real estate is,
and both are subject to confiscation in the United States.
The
More Power a State Has, the More Its Criminal Nature Is Exposed
The very
existence of the state puts humanity on a slippery slope toward
state servitude, grinding poverty, and premature death:
Just
as "the power to tax involves the power to destroy," the
sanctioning of state authority to regulate even one percent
of our conduct is to admit its authority as to the rest.[9]
Ludwig
and Margit von Mises escaped the clutches of the epitome of
totalitarianism: Nazi Germany. It is widely known how murderous
this totalitarian state was. During Ludwig von Mises's lifetime,
the extent of the Communist bloc's criminality and destructiveness
was not known. When The
Black Book of Communism: Crimes, Terror, Repression
was published in 1999, the evil and criminal nature of the
total state, as laid bare by Communism, was exposed for the
whole world to see.
There
is an erroneous mindset that Nazism represents the extreme
right of the political spectrum while Communism represents
the extreme left. This is a mistake, as private-property ownership
and liberty are demolished under the totalitarian state, regardless
of its label. In other words, totalitarianism is totalitarianism.
The authors of The Black Book of Communism drew this
exact conclusion:
One
thing is certain: Crimes against humanity are the product
of an ideology that reduces people not to a universal but
to a particular condition, be it biological, racial, or
sociohistorical. By means of propaganda, the Communists
succeeded in making people believe that their conduct had
universal implications, relevant to humanity as a whole.
Critics have often tried to make a distinction between Nazism
and Communism by arguing that the Nazi project had a particular
aim, which was nationalist and racist in the extreme, whereas
Lenin's project was universal. This is entirely wrong. In
both theory and practice, Lenin and his successors excluded
from humanity all capitalists, the bourgeoisie, counterrevolutionaries,
and others, turning them into absolute enemies in their
sociological and political discourse. Kautsky noted as early
as 1918 that these terms were entirely elastic, allowing
those in power to exclude from humanity whenever they so
wished. These were the terms that led directly to crimes
against humanity.[10]
Under
the total state, there is no private property including ownership
of one's own body. Those exercising power under a totalitarian
regime see nothing wrong with killing people for the sake
of the state. It is no wonder that Communist regimes killed
nearly 100 million people during the 20th century.[11]
The 20th
century, overall, was a bloody one. Dr. R.J. Rummel has coined
the term democide, which means "the murder of any person
or people by a government, including genocide, politicide,
and mass murder."[12]
These deaths do not count combat deaths attributed to war.
In the 20th century, according to Dr. Rummel, democide accounted
for 262 million deaths.[13]
As states
gain power and liberty recedes, the evil, criminal, and murderous
nature of the state becomes self-evident.
All
States Subsist on Coercion and Theft and Are Uneconomic
There
is an assertion that a social contract exists in which individuals
tacitly consent to give up some of their freedoms in exchange
for the benefits of a political order and security as provided
by the state. In reality, who consents to being murdered by
a state in the name of political order? Who consents to being
taxed? Whether an individual is more likely to be murdered
by a state or is merely taxed and bossed around by a state
has everything to do with where someone is born and has nothing
to do with consenting to the dictates of the state.
Taxes
are not voluntary contributions made to the state. Figuratively
speaking, taxes are collected at gunpoint and failure to pay
may land one in prison or worse. Per Lysander Spooner,
If
the government can take a man's money without his consent,
there is no limit to the additional tyranny it may practise
upon him; for, with his money, it can hire soldiers to stand
over him, keep him in subjection, plunder him at discretion,
and kill him if he resists.[14]
What
Spooner described is the unvarnished reality that the state
represents the negation of liberty. For if an individual does
not fully own the fruit of his labor (i.e., money income),
then he lives in a condition of tax slavery.
Taxation
also depresses production. It is a natural response to prevent
a thief from stealing one's belongings. Yet if the thief is
the state, mankind has the inclination to keep as much as
possible away from the government and the economic impact
is deleterious. On this matter, let's turn to Frank Chodorov:
Taxes
of all kinds discourage production. Man works to satisfy
his desires, not to support the state. When the results
of his labor are taken from him, whether by brigands or
organized society, his inclination is to limit his production
to the amount he can keep and enjoy.[15]
Chodorov
further comments,
While
we are on the subject of discouragement of production by
taxation, we should not overlook the greater weight of indirect
taxes, even though it is not so obvious. The production
level of a nation is determined by the purchasing power
of its citizens, and to the extent that this power is sapped
by levies, to that extent is the production level lowered.
It is a silly sophism, and thoroughly indecent, to maintain
that what the state collects it spends, and that therefore
there is no lowering of total purchasing power. Thieves
also spend their loot, with much more abandon than the rightful
owners would have spent it, and on the basis of spending
one could make out a case for the social value of thievery.
It is production, not spending, that begets production.
It is only by the feeding of marketable contributions into
the general fund of wealth that the wheels of industry are
speeded up. Contrariwise, every deduction from this general
fund of wealth slows down industry, and every levy on savings
discourages the accumulation of capital. Why work when there
is nothing to it? Why go into business to support politicians?[16]
A private
company's revenues are derived from spontaneously emergent,
market-based demand (in other words "organic" demand), whereas
a state's revenues arise from theft. States are anticapital,
irrational, and uneconomic in and of themselves.
If there
is any contract that must be broken, it is the alleged social
contract between individuals and the state. Living standards
would rise, due to increased capital accumulation and savings,
which in turn would result in more goods and services being
brought to the market.
Economic
Calculation
What
is economic calculation and why is it important? In Human
Action, Ludwig von Mises succinctly answers these
questions:
The
task which acting man wants to achieve by economic calculation
is to establish the outcome of acting by contrasting input
and output. Economic calculation is either an estimate of
the expected outcome of future action or the establishment
of the outcome of past action. But the latter does not serve
merely historical and didactic aims. Its practical meaning
is to show how much one is free to consume without impairing
the future capacity to produce. It is with regard to this
problem that the fundamental notions of economic calculation
capital and income, profit and loss, spending and
saving, cost and yield are developed. The practical
employment of these notions and of all notions derived from
them is inseparably linked with the operation of a market
in which goods and services of all orders are exchanged
against a universally used medium of exchange, viz., money.
They would be merely academic, without any relevance for
acting within a world with a different structure of action.[17]
In a
territory where the institutions of private property and sound
money are honored, all goods and services can be coherently
exchanged on the free market. Under these conditions, money
prices emerge for both consumer goods and producer goods.
Prices for producer goods are a derivative of the prices of
consumer goods, with the prices of producer goods emerging
through price imputation.[18]
With
private ownership in the means of production, an economy can
flourish. Entrepreneurs can make rational business decisions
and subject such decisions to the profit-and-loss test:
Monetary
calculation is the guiding star of action under the social
system of division of labor. It is the compass of the man
embarking upon production. He calculates in order to distinguish
the remunerative lines of production from the unprofitable
ones, those of which the sovereign consumers are likely
to approve from those which they are likely to disapprove.
Every single step of entrepreneurial activities is subject
to scrutiny by monetary calculation. The premeditation of
planned action becomes commercial precalculation of expected
costs and expected proceeds. The retrospective establishment
of the outcome of past action becomes accounting of profit
and loss.[19]
A tool
businessmen use to determine the success or failure of past
actions is a financial statement, which includes a balance
sheet and an income statement. It is important to understand
that all entries in the balance sheet and income statement
are expressed in terms of money. A businessman can directly
correlate whether his company's capital base (i.e., the company's
net worth as reflected in the balance sheet) is expanding
or contracting depending on if the company turned a profit
or made a loss. Such monetary calculation assists a businessman
in deciding to maintain or change a business plan based on
satisfying the ever-sovereign consumer.
In business,
a private company can gauge the demand for its products through
its sales volume. Using generally accepted accounting principles
(GAAP), sales are recorded as the very top entry of an income
statement (also known as a profit-and-loss statement) using
the term "revenues." Revenues are generated through the voluntary
exchanges of money, from customers, in return for the products
sold to customers. A company will know quickly if there is
a demand for its product for if sales do not materialize
or are significantly below expectations, then the company's
revenues will reflect this lack of customer demand. A revenue
shortfall, in turn, most likely will reveal a company with
an unprofitable business model in which revenues fall short
of covering production and overhead costs. Hence, the income
statement will reveal a net loss. The company's capital base
will shrink as a result of this loss.
A GAAP
income statement, for a private company, would look like the
following:
- Revenues
- Cost
of Revenues Earned
- Gross
Profit
- General
and Administrative Expenses
- Net
Income from Operations
- Other
Income (Expenses)
- Net
Income (Loss)
- Retained
Earnings, Beginning of Year
- Retained
Earnings, End of Year
If the
company turns a net income, its retained earnings will increase,
thus resulting in an increase of the company's capital base.
If the company turns a net loss, then retained earnings will
shrink and this results in the diminution of its capital base.
This is the elegance of economic calculation.
The
State Cannot Calculate
All states
are extramarket constructs and are always and everywhere incapable
of economic calculation. Without the profit-and-loss test,
with private property being a prerequisite, socialism does
not allow an economy to emerge. Socialism is, therefore, irrational.
If a state allows private-property ownership within its territory,
and a free-market economy emerges, it does not follow that
such a state is rational. For such a state is incapable of
rationally allocating resources under its command, as public
entities do not have the ability to measure their performance
through the profit-and-loss test. Public entities, ultimately,
depend on coercion and theft to fund themselves and their
programs. Hence, the mindset of bureaucrats is political and
not economic in character.
In a
world of scarcity, rational resource allocation is critical
to supporting human life. For those of a political mindset,
should we expect rationality and logic with respect to matters
of economics?
Rational
conduct would be divorced from the very ground which is
its proper domain. Would there, in fact, be any such thing
as rational conduct at all, or, indeed, such a thing as
rationality and logic in thought itself? Historically, human
rationality is a development of economic life. Could it
then obtain when divorced therefrom?[20]
In states
where private property is allowed, there exists a false perception
that state bureaucrats can rationally allocate resources.
This is an illusion foisted on a gullible public. If a public
entity runs a surplus, it is hailed as being operated responsibly.
If the public entity runs a deficit, it is seen as a problem
that must be rectified by the bureaucrats in charge.
Public-sector
accounting does measure revenues and expenses. There is, however,
no profit-and-loss test precisely because a state or public
entity is not a market-based phenomenon. Public-sector accounting,
accordingly, is purely self-referential in that state operatives
desire to know if enough money is being skimmed from its subjects
in order to remain viable. Public-sector accounting also provides
an air of respectability in that public entities want to promote
the illusion of accountability to the populace. The objectives
of public-sector accounting are conveyed as follows:
Traditional
objectives:
- To
provide a financial summary
- To
enable detailed comparisons of spending to be made with
the budget
- To
allow the identification of spending to ensure it complies
with the law and other legal authorities
- To
provide the basis for the next budget
Modern
objectives:
- To
inform the stakeholders about the financial situation
of the government
- To
provide possible investors with information about creditworthiness
- To
aid management decision making
- To
identify assets and liabilities
- To
facilitate democratic transparency[21]
Note
such terms and concepts as compliance with the law, budgeting,
stakeholders, creditworthiness, and democratic transparency;
throw in the term "sustainability" and public-relations perfection
will have been achieved.
Services
most often associated with the public sector are police protection,
security, legal system, roads, national defense, and money
production. Of course, there are numerous welfare programs
such as Social Security and Medicare but these are
not services in that they are pure transfers of wealth.
To reiterate,
because a state's revenues are generated through coercion,
via taxation, there is no way of gauging any organic demand
for the services the state provides to its populace. Without
a legitimate gauge for measuring the demand for a state's
services, as there is no connection between demand and revenues
(such as there is in private enterprise), a state has absolutely
no means of calculating if it is rationally allocating resources.
It also
follows that because state services cannot be tested against
the metrics of organic demand, then it is impossible for state
bureaucrats to know if they are meeting the most urgent needs
of the populace; it is impossible for taxes to act as a substitute
for market-generated revenues. Only market-based revenues
serve to provide the signals of how much and what type of
services are actually demanded by people.
In the
United States, for example, there has materialized a web of
public entities municipal, state, and national
that has parasitically fastened to a market society
siphoning resources away from where countless individuals
would have otherwise directed their own money and resources.
How many smart bombs, drones, fighter jets, military bases,
policemen, judges, social workers, CIA spies, and IRS agents
are demanded by John Q. Public? Whether or not a public entity
runs a surplus or a deficit does not answer this question.
Because a state is not a market-based phenomenon, although
it still may be able to gauge its expenses using prices that
have emerged on the free market, it can never gauge the demand
for its services as a state's top-line income is derived from
theft and not from free-market demand. This lattice work of
public entities, therefore, serves to misallocate resources
on an enormous scale.
State-Controlled
Money versus the Free Market
Per Ludwig
von Mises's regression theorem,
money,
in any society, can only become established by a market
process emerging from barter. Money cannot be established
by a social contract, by government imposition, or by artificial
schemes proposed by economists. Money can only emerge, "organically"
so to speak, out of the market.[22]
Contra
to what public officials and statists assert, there is no
economic law prohibiting the private production of money,[23]
let alone security services,[24]
defense,[25]
justice,[26]
and roads.[27]
Yet governments, being the criminal enterprises that they
are, have succeeded in supplanting market-based money (gold
and silver) with fiat money.
With
the emergence of the state came the multicentury process of
governments gaining control over monetary systems. Such usurpations
typically began with the state seizing absolute control of
the minting business with the state naming the monetary
unit to separate it from the underlying weight of the coin
(which opens the door for coinage debasement). The next step
was for states to enact legal-tender laws dictating what money
could be. As money substitutes were brought into widespread
use, in recent centuries, governments gave banks the privilege
of suspending payment in specie. All of this set the table
to bring central banking into the picture, whereby governments
grant central banks a monopoly on the note of issue.[28]
Directly
due to the effects of central banking, stock-market bubbles
arose in the United States in the 1920s, the 1980s, and the
late 1990s /early 2000s. Each bubble was fueled by the Federal
Reserve's easy-money policies and led directly to the Great
Depression,[29]
the record stock-market crash of 1987, and the crash of the
NASDAQ/dot-com bubble, which imploded over the period of 20002001.[30]
The Austrian theory of the trade cycle provides the only explanation
for these booms and busts. As Roger Garrison explains,
The
Austrian theory of the business cycle emerges straightforwardly
from a simple comparison of savings-induced growth, which
is sustainable, with a credit-induced boom, which is not.
An increase in saving by individuals and a credit expansion
orchestrated by the central bank set into motion market
processes whose initial allocational effects on the economy's
capital structure are similar. But the ultimate consequences
of the two processes stand in stark contrast: Saving gets
us genuine growth; credit expansion gets us boom and bust.[31]
Famously,
after the attacks of 9/11, Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
reduced the federal-funds rate (which stood at 6.5 percent
in November of 2000) to 1 percent in July of 2003. The federal-funds
rate remained at 1 percent until June of 2004.[32]
Such artificially low interest rates stimulated a housing
bubble as enabled by the government-sponsored enterprises
of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Frank
Shostak eloquently describes how loose monetary policy was
the proximate cause of America's housing bubble:
We
can define a bubble as activities that spring up on the
back of loose monetary policy of the central bank. In other
words, in the absence of monetary pumping these activities
would not emerge. Since bubble activities are not self-funded,
their emergence must come at the expense of various self-funded
or productive activities. This means that less real funding
is left for productive activities, which in turn undermines
those activities. In short, monetary pumping gives rise
to the misallocation of resources, which as a rule manifests
itself through a relative increase in non-productive activities
against productive activities.[33]
Accordingly,
the mass delusion that a long-term consumer durable, such
as a house, will increase in price, year after year, directly
emanated from the Federal Reserve's monetary pumping. The
bubble-headed assumption that housing prices would never decline
demonstrates that easy money certainly led to a massive clustering
of error, culminating in a terrible bust in the housing market.
By September
of 2008, the Federal Reserve's easy-money policy came home
to roost when major American financial institutions recognized
that their balance sheets were in tatters. Reckless lending
for home mortgages led to widespread mortgage-loan defaults.
Because Wall Street had turned into a mortgage-debt securitization
machine and American financial institutions' balance sheets
were stuffed full of such mortgage-backed securities
whose prices dropped precipitously, due to the aforementioned
loan defaults money-center banks and powerhouse Wall
Street firms were brought to their knees.
On October
14, 2008, "the U.S. government announced a series of initiatives
to strengthen market stability, improve the strength of financial
institutions, and enhance market liquidity."[34]
The cornerstone initiative was the "Troubled Asset Relief
Program (TARP), in which the secretary of the Treasury would
expend as much as $700 billion in two installments to purchase
rotten paper, such as mortgage-backed derivatives, from banks
and other financial institutions."[35]
Wall
Street titans such as Citigroup, Goldman Sachs, and JPMorgan
Chase initially felt the pain of the 2008 economic collapse.
However, because such financial institutions were deemed "too
big to fail," Secretary of the Treasury Hank Paulson saw to
it that these insolvent behemoths were bailed out at the expense
of Main Street. Robert Murphy concludes,
The
TARP was crooked from the very start, using taxpayer funds
to bail out some of the world's richest people from their
own foolish investments. The claims that it made taxpayers
money are unfounded. Even worse, TARP taught investment
bankers an important lesson: During a boom, make as much
money as you can, no matter how short-term the profits will
be. When the bubble pops, the Treasury and Fed will be there
with a taxpayer-funded pillow.[36]
When
government controls money, through a central bank, combined
with the power to tax, the criminal activities undertaken
by the state can be nothing short of audacious and supremely
damaging.
Under
a free market, where gold and silver coins are privately minted
and used as money, such state-induced boom-bust cycles, as
exemplified by America's housing bubble, could not emerge.
Conversely, when the criminal enterprise, known as the state,
controls the production of money, history illustrates how
economically destructive the state can be.
Conclusion
As a
state grows, the free market becomes hampered and recedes.
Because all states are incapable of rationally allocating
resources under their command, it logically follows that the
total state must snuff out an economy altogether. When Economic
Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth was published,
Mises's "seminal journal article in 1920 on the impossibility
of economic calculation under socialism was the most important
critique ever leveled at socialism."[37]
Fundamental to this critique was the absolute necessity of
private ownership in the means of production.
Ludwig
von Mises, therefore, was a fierce defender of private-property
ownership. For without private property, an economy cannot
emerge:
It
is an illusion to imagine that in a socialist state calculation
in natura can take place of monetary calculation.
Calculation in natura, in an economy without exchange,
can embrace consumption goods only; it completely fails
when it comes to dealing with goods of a higher order. And
as soon as one gives up the conception of a freely established
monetary price for goods of a higher order, rational production
becomes completely impossible. Every step that takes us
away from private ownership of the means of production and
from the use of money also takes us away from rational economics.[38]
(Emphasis in the original)
Mises
did not, however, view socialism as systematized robbery.[39]
Had he been aware of the Soviet Union's brutal treatment of
kulaks during its collectivization process, it is possible
he would have changed his mind. Per The Black Book of Communism,
Recent
research in the newly accessible archives has confirmed
that the forced collectivization of the countryside was
in effect a war declared by the Soviet state on a nation
of smallholders. More than 2 million peasants were deported
(1.8 million in 193031 alone), 6 million died of hunger,
and hundreds of thousands died as a direct result of deportation.[40]
Such
shocking information may have jarred Mises into grasping that
all states, by definition, exist based on systematized robbery
and violence. In turn, any entity whose very existence depends
on systematized theft and coercion inherently must misallocate
resources and destroy capital. In a world of scarcity, such
an institution must be deemed antihuman and irrational. Socialism,
accordingly, isn't the problem; the state itself is.
Mises,
to be sure, had serious misgivings about the state:
Private
property creates for the individual a sphere in which he
is free of the state. It sets limits to the operation of
the authoritarian will. It allows other forces to arise
side by side with and in opposition to political power.
It thus becomes the basis of all those activities that are
free from violent interference on the part of the state.
It is the soil in which the seeds of freedom are nurtured
and in the autonomy of the individual and ultimately all
intellectual and material progress are rooted.[41]
Inherent
to private property is the right to self-ownership, "a right
held by everyone by virtue of being a human being."[42]
Every person, in other words, has a property right in his
own body. By extending Mises's view of private property to
each person's body, the sphere in which mankind would maximize
freedom along with intellectual and material progress would
be where no state exists at all.
Bibliography
-
Block,
Walter, 2009, "Road Socialism," The Privatization of
Roads and Highways: Human and Economic Factors, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
-
Carabini,
Louis E., 2008, Inclined to Liberty: The Futile Attempt
to Suppress the Human Spirit, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von
Mises Institute.
-
-
Chodorov,
Frank, 1974, The Income Tax: Root of all Evil,
Old Greenwich, CT: The Devin-Adair Company.
-
Chodorov,
Frank, 2007a, Out of Step, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von
Mises Institute.
-
Chodorov,
Frank, 2007b, The Rise & Fall of Society, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Courtois,
Stephane, et al., 1999, The Black Book of Communism:
Crimes, Terror, Repression, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
-
De
Soto, Jesus Huerta, 2010, Socialism, Economic Calculation
and Entrepreneurship, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar
Publishing.
-
De
Soto, Jesus Huerta, 2006, Money, Bank Credit, and Economic
Cycles, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
-
Fergusson,
Adam, 2010, When Money Dies: The Nightmare of Deficit
Spending, Devaluation, and Hyperinflation in Weimar Germany,
New York, NY: PublicAffairs.
-
Garrison,
Roger W., 1996, "The Austrian Theory: A Summary," in The
Austrian Theory of the Trade Cycle and Other Essays,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Garrison,
Roger W., 2001, Time and Money: The Macroeconomics
of Capital Structure, New York, NY: Routledge.
-
Gordon,
David, 1990, Resurrecting Marx: The Analytical Marxists
on Freedom, Exploitation, and Justice, New Brunswick,
NJ: Transaction Publishers.
-
Gordon,
David, 2007, "Introduction," in Secession, State &
Liberty, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
-
Hayek,
F.A., 1991, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism,
Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.
-
Hepworth,
Noel, 2003, "Accounting in the Public Sector," Chartered
Institute of Public Finance and Accountancy, University
of Malta.
-
-
Hoppe,
Hans-Hermann, 2002, Democracy, The God that Failed:
The Economics and Politics of Monarchy, Democracy, and
Natural Order, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
-
Hoppe,
Hans-Hermann, 2003, "Government and the Private Production
of Defense," in The Myth of National Defense: Essays
on the Theory and History of Security Production,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Hoppe,
Hans-Hermann, 2006, The Economics and Ethics of Private
Property: Studies in Political Economy and Philosophy,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Hulsmann,
Jorg Guido, 1997, "Knowledge, Judgment, and the Use of
Property," Review of Austrian Economics, 10, 1.
-
Hulsmann,
Jorg Guido, 2007, Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Hulsmann,
Jorg Guido, 2008a, Deflation & Liberty, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Hulsmann,
Jorg Guido, 2008b, The Ethics of Money Production,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Mahoney,
Dan, 2002, "Ownership, Scarcity, and Economic Decision
Making," The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics,
5, 1.
-
Mahoney,
Dan, 2005, "On Austrian Value Theory and Economic Calculation,"
Working Paper.
-
Maltsev,
Yuri N., 1993, "Introduction," Requiem for Marx,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1977, Planned Chaos, Irvington-On-Hudson,
NY: The Foundation for Economic Education.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1981a, Socialism: An Economic and Sociological
Analysis, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1981b, The Theory of Money and Credit,
Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1983, Bureaucracy, Grove City, PA:
Libertarian Press.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1985, Liberalism: In the Classical Tradition,
Irvington-On-Hudson, NY: The Foundation for Economic Education.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1990, Economic Calculation in the Socialist
Commonwealth, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 1998, Human Action, Auburn, AL: Ludwig
von Mises Institute.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 2003, Epistemological Problems of Economics,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Mises,
Ludwig von, 2006, The Causes of the Economic Crisis:
And Other Essays Before and After the Great Depression,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
-
Murphy,
Robert P., 2011, Study Guide to The Theory of Money
& Credit by Ludwig von Mises, Auburn, AL: Ludwig
von Mises Institute.
-
Notten,
Michael van, 2006, The Law of the Somalis: A Stable
Foundation for Economic Development in the Horn of Africa,
Trenton, NJ: The Red Sea Press.
-
Oppenheimer,
Franz, 1999, The State: Its History and Development
Viewed Sociologically, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Publishers.
-
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1988, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator,
Hero, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1990, What Has Government Done to Our Money?,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1991a, The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1991b, "The End of Socialism and the Calculation
Debate Revisited," The Review of Austrian Economics,
5, 2.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1994, The Case Against the Fed, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 1998, The Ethics of Liberty, New York,
NY: New York University
-
Press.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 2000, America's Great Depression, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 2004, Man, Economy, & State: A Treatise
on Economic Principles: with Power and Market, Government
and the Economy, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 2006, For a New Liberty: The Libertarian
Manifesto, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rothbard,
Murray N., 2007, The Panic of 1819: Reactions and Policies,
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Rummel,
Rudolph available at http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rudolph_Rummel.
-
Salerno,
Joseph T., 1993, "Mises and Hayek Dehomogenized," The
Review of Austrian Economics, 6, 2.
-
Salerno,
Joseph T., 1999, "The Place of Mises's Human Action
in the Development of Modern Economic Thought," The
Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 2, 1.
-
-
-
Shaffer,
Butler, 2009, Boundaries of Order: Private Property
as a Social System, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
-
Spooner,
Lysander, 1852, Trial by Jury, Cleveland, OH: Jewett,
Proctor, & Worthington.
-
Steele,
David Ramsay, 1981, "Posing the Problem: The Impossibility
of Economic Calculation under Socialism," The Journal
of Libertarian Studies, V, 1.
-
Strigl,
Richard von, 2000, Capital & Production, Auburn,
AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
-
Tannehill,
Linda and Morris, 1993, The Market for Liberty,
San Francisco, CA: Fox & Wilkes.
-
Thornton,
Mark, "The Economics of Housing Bubbles," Auburn, AL:
Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Notes
[1]
Rothbard (1998), pp. 3738.
[2]
For an excellent analysis of Economic Calculation in
the Socialist Commonwealth, read Joseph T. Salerno's
postscript titled "Why a Socialist Economy is 'Impossible.'"
Mises (1990), pp. 5171.
[3]
Mises (1983), p. 27.
[4]
Tannehill (1993), p. 113.
[5]
Oppenheimer (1999), pp. 2425.
[6]
Ibid p. 27.
[7]
Maltsev (1993), p. 25.
[8]
Courtois, et al. (1999), p. 4.
[9]
Shaffer (2009), p. 282.
[10]
Courtois, et al. (1999), pp. 752753.
[11]
Ibid p. 4.
[12]
Wikipedia Rudolph Rummel.
[13]
Ibid.
[14]
Spooner (1852), Appendix.
[15]
Chodorov (2007a), p. 225.
[16]
Chodorov (2007a), pp. 225226.
[17]
Mises (1998), pp. 211212.
[18]
See Dan Mahoney On Austrian Value Theory and Economic
Calculation.
[19]
Mises (1998), p. 230.
[20]
Mises (1990), p. 21.
[21]
See Noel Hepworth: Chartered Institute of Public Finance
and Accountancy, University of Malta, February 2003
[22]
Rothbard (1988), p. 19.
[23]
See Jorg Guido Hulsmann's The Ethics of Money Production
"Monetary Reform" pp. 240242.
[24]
See Linda and Morris Tannehill's The Market for Liberty
Chapter 8 "Protection of Life and Property."
[25]
See Hans-Hermann Hoppe's Chapter 10 "Government and the
Private Production of Defense" in The Myth of National
Defense: Essays on the Theory and History of Security Production.
[26]
See Michael van Notten's The Law of the Somalis Chapters
3, 4, and 5.
[27]
See Walter Block's chapter "Road Socialism" in The Privatization
of Roads and Highways edited by Walter Block.
[28]
Rothbard (1990), pp. 5769.
[29]
See Murray Rothbard's America's Great Depression.
[30]
See Mark Thornton's The Economics of Housing Bubbles
p. 21.
[31]
Garrison (1996), p. 112.
[32]
See Mark Thornton's The Economics of Housing Bubbles
p. 15.
[33]
Shostak (2003), p. 1.
[34]
See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Troubled
Asset Relief Program (TARP) Information.
[35]
Higgs (2008), p. 1.
[36]
Murphy (2010), p. 7.
[37]
Rothbard (1988), p. 25.
[38]
Mises (1990), pp. 1920.
[39]
Hulsmann (2007), p. 445.
[40]
Courtois, et al. (1999), p. 146.
[41]
Mises (1985), pp. 6768.
[42]
Rothbard (2006), p. 35.
September
7, 2011
|